A Contract Among States: Capturing Income of the World's Multijurisdictional Taxpayers

AutoreNatasha Varyani
CaricaVisiting Assistant Professor at Boston University School of Law
Pagine219-241
ARTICLES & ESSAYS
DOI 10.6092/issn.2531-6133/6455
UNIVERSITY OF BOLOGNA LAW REVIEW
ISSN 2531-6133
[VOL.1:2 2016]
This article is released under the terms of Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License
219
A Contract among States: Capturing Income of the World’s
Multijurisdictional Taxpayers
NATASHA N. VARYANI
TABLE OF CO NTENTS: 1. Managing Jurisdictions in an Evolving Economy; 2. The Multistate
Tax Compact; 2.1. Mission and Goals; 2.2. Congressional Consent and the Authority of
the Compact; 2.3. Articles III and IV: Election and Three Factor Apportionment; 2.4.
Modern Use of the Multistate Tax Compact; 3. State Courts Respond to Taxpayer
Elections; 3.1. I.B.M. in Michigan; 3.2. Gillette in California; 3.3. Kimberly-Clark in
Minnesota; 3.4. Amici Cur and Other Stakeholders; 4. The Future of the Multistate
Tax Compact.
ABSTRACT: Systems for managing multiple taxing jurisdictions in a larger group are
working to keep up with the evolution of the modern multijurisdictional taxpayer.
Recent decisions from the high cour ts of several states have brought attention to a
meaningful tension in the goals of the Multistate Tax Compact, an agreement between
states. Though the federal government has ruled that no congressional approval is
necessary based on the Compact Clause of the U.S. Constitution, this agreement
between states has taken its place as a significant accord among the vast majority of
jurisdictions. Having operated as the most effective solution to the problems identified
by Congress in the 1960’s Willis Report, the Compact simultaneously disavows its
binding authority and relies on States meet its goal of promoting uniformity in state
tax administration. With billions of dollars of much needed tax revenue at issue, this
article seeks to examine the intricacies of the legal principles applied to this contract
among states while understanding its role in the modern economy, both within the
United States and beyond.
KEYWORDS: Multistate Tax Compact; Multi-Jurisdictional Tax; Apportionment; Compact Clause;
State Tax.
University of Bologna Law Review
[Vol.1:2 2016]
DOI 10.6092/issn.2531-6133/6455
220
Interstate commerce is a rich tax base.
It has, moreover, special political fascination.
A state or local tax levied upon it falls largely upon people in other states.
Here is a legislator’s dream: a lush source of tax revenue,
the burden of which falls largely on those who cannot vote him out of office.
1
1. MANAGING JURISDICTION IN AN EVOLVING ECONOMY
The way in which businesses conduct themselves across jurisdictional lines
both globally and nationally has rapidly evolved alongside technology. The
question of how to manage multiple taxing jurisdictions within a group has
given rise to some tensions that arise from our form of government. From the
inception of the United States,
2
courts and legislatures have grappled with the
problem of creating a series of tax rules in various jurisdictions
3
that work
together to create a fair, predictable and organized system that will result in
the free flow of commerce between and among jurisdictions while
appropriately compensating the relevant governments.
4
The European Union,
despite many relevant distinctions, may glean some applicable principals
about the tension between allowing each jurisdiction the independence to
create and administer their own tax laws while seeking conformity with a
larger system designed for a group of jurisdictions.
After the U.S. Supreme Court’s 1959 ruling in Northwestern States
Portland Cement Co. v. Minnesota, which held that net income of a foreign
corporation may be taxed by a state if that tax is fairly apportioned, Congress
commissioned a study which later became known as the “Willis Report” and
passed P.L. 86-272. The legislation that was enacted was intended to be a
“stopgap” measure until the question could be properly addressed recently
Visiting Assistant Professor at Boston University School of Law. Special thanks to Leanne Scott,
Michael Fatale, Kevin McGrath, and to Boston University Law School, without whose gracious
support this article would not have been possible.
1
Wallace Mendelson, Epilogue to FELIX FRANKFURTER, THE COMMERCE CLAUSE UNDER MARSHALL, TANEY
AND WAITE 118 (Quadrangle Books 1964)(1937).
2
See THE FEDERALIST NOS. 30-36 (Alexander Hamilton).: balancing authority to tax of individual
states. See also U.S. CONST. amend. XIV, § 1. See also U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8, cl. 3
3
The Commerce Clause grants authority to Congress to limit the ability of the individual states to
impose a tax where such tax would be a burden on interstate commerce. The “Dormant”
Commerce Clause has developed by judicial opinion and has become an accepted grant of authority
to the Federal government to limit powers of individual states to tax even in the absence of
Federal legislation.
4
See U.S. Constitution Commerce Clause, see also International Harvester Co. v. Wis. Dep't of
Taxation, 322 U.S. 435 (1944); Northwestern Cement Co. v. Minnesota, 358 U.S. 450 (1959); Quill
Corp. v. North Dakota, 504 U.S. 298 (1992).

Per continuare a leggere

RICHIEDI UNA PROVA

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT